Econdiscussion
  • Home
  • Articles
  • About Me

Articles

“Economics and democracy” – The Economist

16/3/2016

1 Comment

 
Synopsis: How economics has shaped the evolution of politics.

Click here to read the original article. 

Discussion:


This article discusses the history of prevalent economic thought and its effects on politics. Throughout history, politicians have adopted only those economic policies that allow them to stay in power. In this way, a country’s economic issues can be viewed through the “prism of the political structure.”

19th Century:

Political scenario: Wealthy creditors with no real interest in the government were concerned with “maintaining the real value of their money”, as can be seen by the use of the gold standard (explained in Key Terms) and their one allowance of government intervention, through the use of the central bank, to ensure the success of the financial system.

Economic climate: Classical theory dominated economics. Classical theory concerned itself with the self-correcting nature of an economy (explained in Context), and thus reasoned that the government had little place in the free market.

1914 – 1929:

Political scenario: World War I (1914-1918) resulted in the sudden need for ammunition and manpower. The brief respite during the Roaring Twenties was overshadowed by the Great Depression, which began in 1929.

Economic climate: Government intervention, high inflation and debt during World War I destroyed classical theory. Any attempts to rebuild classical theory during the twenties were outweighed by the Great Depression: there was great reluctance by mass democracies to put the strain of the gold standard on the already suffering working class.
​
1930s and 40s:

Political scenario: In the aftermath of the Great Depression, economies did not return to full employment. This was a great cause for concern among politicians, and the worry was carried into World War II.

Economic climate: Popular economist J.M. Keynes focused on government spending to boost demand, and thus, lower unemployment, through the use of fiscal policy (explained under Key Terms). This theory gained traction during World War II, where government intervention increased greatly and unemployment was wrestled down to a manageable level. Welfare states (explained in Key Terms) seemed like a small concession compared to the threat of communism (explained in Context).

1960s and 70s:

Political scenario: The rapid rise of inflation led politicians to believe that the government focus on unemployment was wrong. Middle-class voters, angry at high taxes, were quick to support an economic reform. Reagan and Thatcher adopted new policies quickly, with Europe following later, having been shaken by the scare of Eurosclerosis (explained under Key Terms).

Economic climate: The previously successful Phillips curve (explained under Context) was falling apart. Milton Friedman and his followers thus argued that governments should shift their focus away from controlling unemployment and towards managing inflation through controlling the money supply. Supply-side economics (explained in Key Terms) became popular quickly, as did monetary policy, which led to an active central bank.

1980s and 90s:

Political scenario: The fall of inflation resulted in a reputation boost for central bankers, despite the fact that inflation may have decreased due to China’s entry into the global economy (explained under Context). Reagan's and Thatcher’s reforms were well underway, which led to a rise in the debt-to-GDP ratio.

Economic climate: Reagan's and Thatcher’s reforms meant the recognition of the financial sector as a key player in any economy.

1987:

Political scenario: The riskiness of the system that ensued from the increasing debt-to-GDP ratio encourage central banks to cut interest rates during any period of uncertainty, as was seen on Black Monday.

Economic climate: Economic actors interpreted central banks’ nervous response to a wobbly economy as their “[underwriting of] asset prices”. Buying assets with borrowed money seemed to be the quick and easy way to make fortunes.

1990s:

Political scenario: The end of fixed exchange rates, and along with it, capital controls (explained in Context) made global finance very powerful, as money could easily enter and exit economies and sectors. At the same time, the wealth of the financial sector allowed its key players to fund and win favour of the political elite.

Economic climate: The loss of control over capital flows turned government focus towards dissuading capital flight, while the wealth of the financial sector meant that politics supported economic policy that favoured financial markets.

1980s to 2007:

Political scenario: The threat of communism fell along with the Soviet Union. Center-right politicians who had acquiesced to government regulation during the Great Depression gained political power, while center-left politicians supported more right-wing policies. At the same time, trade-union power fell, partially due to globalization, and partially due to the “relative decline in manufacturing”. Organizing protests became harder when many of its remaining members were dispersed across different jobs in different economies.

Economic climate: Right-wing economic policies such as the freedom for free markets to function with minimal intervention were established. The decline in trade-union power and blue-collar worker votes resulted in the larger economic actors having a greater say in shaping economic policy. It is no surprise that today we see the central banks and other large institutions as the most powerful actors in our economies.

During this time, mainstream economic theory became more micro-based as well as mathematical, despite the rise of behavioural economics.

2008 on:

The aftermath of the Great Financial Crisis has taught us that debt and the financial sector should be more central to macroeconomics and macroeconomic policy. Popular policy focus now is on attacking and trying to prevent the effects of globalization, such as the movement of jobs away from developed economies to countries that provide cheap labor. The problem is that globalization has already happened, and its effects are already underway. What will determine the success of globalization is how the Chinese economy will deal with its financial system and whether the Federal Reserve will withdraw its monetary stimulus effectively.

Just as politicians have always reacted to the economic climate, we may find that our future economic state may be a shift away from globalization and towards nationalism.

​Key terms:

1. Gold standard: A system in which the value of currency is fixed in terms of gold, and could be traded in for gold.

2. Fiscal policy: the process of government spending to stimulate demand (fiscal expansion) or government saving to decrease debt (austerity).

3. Welfare state: Where the state plays a pivotal role in protecting and promoting the economy and its citizens.

4. Eurosclerosis: A term coined in the 70s by Herbert Giersch to describe the state of stagnation in Europe that may have resulted from over-regulation by the government.

5. Supply-side economics: also known as “trickle-down economics” and “Reaganomics” – the latter due to Reagan’s active promotion of supply-side economics – argues that production is the most important determinant of economic growth. For this reason, investors and businessmen should face less barriers to production and investment through lower taxes.

Context:

​1. Classical theory: The self-correcting nature of markets was first alluded to by the father of Classical theory, Adam Smith. The idea is that prices adjust themselves and equilibrium is regained in the economy.
Picture
Suppose this is the market for a good X. Initially, the supply of X is denoted by S, and the demand denoted by D1. The resulting price P1 and quantity Q1 is shown by the intersection of D1 and S at equilibrium point A.

Now, demand for X increases to D2. At the original price P1, more of X is demanded, resulting in quantity demanded Q3. This is point B. Seeing the increase in demand, suppliers increase the price of X to increase their profits. Now, fewer people can afford the good, but enough people still want more of the good that suppliers feel like they can increase the price. Still fewer people can afford the good, but suppliers can still increase the price. This process, indicated by the red arrows, continues until the economy adjusts to a new equilibrium C, where all the demand is met by supply. Classical economists refer to this as the work of the invisible hand, guiding the economy from one equilibrium to another.

While the theory of the invisible hand is often attributed to Adam Smith, Smith used it as a term to
discuss international trade, and did not mean it to be the process described above. Still, Smith, along with other classical economists like David Ricardo and John Stuart Mill, believed the economy to be self-correcting.

2. Why would the presence of a welfare state result be a small price to pay in the face of the threat of communism? During the Great Depression, it is the democratic countries that suffered, while communist countries seemed to be fairing better. To ensure that communism does not dominate democratic countries, the government had to ameliorate the economic situation by being heavily involved in the economy.

3. To learn more about the Phillips curve and its failure in the U.S. economy, read my article here.

4. Why did China’s entry into the global economy decrease inflation? Not only were cheap goods and services provided by China, but so was cheap labor. For this reason, costs of goods, services and labor fell around the world, resulting in decreased inflation.

5. Why would the end of the fixed exchange rate system lead to the end of capital controls? Under a fixed exchange rate regime, high levels of reserves are needed to keep the exchange rate from fluctuating. For example, Hong Kong needs high levels of reserves for its currency to remain pegged to the U.S. dollar. If, for some reason, Hong Kong becomes less appealing to investors, the demand for the Hong Kong dollar will decrease, and the reserves will deplete. Capital controls are needed to make sure sudden capital influx or capital flight does not deplete the reserves, and thus, the exchange rate.
1 Comment

    Categories

    All
    Abenomics
    Adam Smith
    Adverse Selection
    Ageing
    Amazon
    Arrows
    Arthur Okun
    Asset
    Asymmetric Information
    Ben Bernanke
    Booms And Busts
    Braess' Paradox
    Brazil
    Bretton Woods
    Brexit
    Bubble
    Bull Market
    Business Cycle
    Capital Control
    Capital Flows
    Capital In The Twenty First Century
    Capital In The Twenty-First Century
    Carry Trade
    Causation
    Central Bank
    China
    Christopher Sims
    Classical Economics
    Consumption
    Counter-cyclical
    CPI
    Creative Destruction
    Crisis
    Daron Acemoglu
    David Cameron
    David Ricardo
    Debt
    Debt-to-GDP
    Deflation
    Deleverage Cycle
    Demography
    Devaluation
    Developing Economies
    Development
    Diffusion
    Diminishing Returns
    Dominant Strategy
    Dominated Strategy
    ECB
    Economic History
    Economic Theory
    Equality
    Equitity
    Equity
    Equity Investments
    EU
    Exchange Rate
    FDI
    Fed
    Federal Reserve
    Finance
    Financial Crisis
    Financial Instability Hypothesis
    Financial-instability Hypothesis
    Financial Times
    Fiscal Multiplier
    Fiscal Policy
    Fixed Exchange Rate
    Fleming
    Floating Exchange Rate
    Free Market
    Free Trade
    Freshwater
    Game Theory
    GDP
    George Akerlof
    Germany
    GFC
    Gini Coefficient
    Global Financial Crisis
    Globalization
    Government Intervention
    Government Spending
    Great Depression
    Growth
    Heckscher-Ohlin
    Helene Rey
    Hyman Minsky
    ICOR
    Illiquid
    Immigration
    Income
    Inequality
    Inflation
    Infrastructure
    Innovation
    Interest Rates
    Investment
    Italy
    James Robinson
    Janet Yellen
    Japan
    Jean Tirole
    J.M. Keynes
    John Nash
    Keynesian Economics
    Labor
    Lawrence Summers
    Leverage
    Lindau
    Liquid
    Malaysia
    Managed Exchange Rate
    Mario Draghi
    Matteo Renzi
    Michael Spense
    Minsky Moment
    Mixed Strategy
    Monetary Policy
    Monopoly
    Monopsony
    Moral Hazard
    Mundell
    Mundell-Fleming Trilemma
    Nash
    Nash Equilibrium
    Nigeria
    Nobel
    Nobel Laureates
    Nobel Prize
    Paul Krugman
    Paul Samuelson
    Perfect Information
    Phillips Curve
    Politics
    Poverty Traps
    Principal Agent Problem
    Prisoner's Dilemma
    Productivity
    Protectionism
    QE
    Qualitative Easing
    Quantitative Easing
    Redistribution
    Regulation
    Retrenching
    Rich
    Risk
    Robert Shiller
    Saltwater
    Saving
    Secular Stagnation
    Shiller
    Shinzo Abe
    Signaling
    Stakeholders
    Stolper-Samuelson Theorem
    Strategy
    Subsidies
    Tariff
    Taxation
    Taxes
    The Economist
    The Market For Lemons
    Theory Of Comparative Advantage
    Thomas Piketty
    Total Factor Productivity
    Trade
    Trilemma
    UK
    Unemployment
    U.S.
    USD
    Wage Benefits
    Wages
    Wealth
    Wealth Effect
    Wolfgang Stolper
    WTO
    Yuan

    Author

    JANANI DHILEEPAN
    A gap year student trying to explore real-world economics

    Archives

    May 2018
    February 2018
    January 2018
    December 2017
    November 2017
    April 2017
    February 2017
    December 2016
    October 2016
    September 2016
    August 2016
    July 2016
    May 2016
    March 2016
    January 2016
    November 2015
    September 2015
    August 2015
    July 2015
    June 2015
    April 2015
    March 2015
    February 2015
    January 2015
    December 2014
    November 2014
    October 2014
    September 2014

    RSS Feed

Proudly powered by Weebly