Econdiscussion
  • Home
  • Articles
  • About Me

Articles

The High Cost of Free Products

16/5/2018

0 Comments

 
​Regulators must look beyond prices to control the anticompetitive behaviour in tech industries
 
“If you’re not paying for it, you are the product,” goes the Silicon Valley saying. While consumers have been enjoying the free products offered by tech firms, Europeans are leading the world in regulating the anticompetitive behaviour of tech companies. The competition commissioner for the European Union, Margrethe Vestager, has established herself as the de-facto worldwide tech regulator.
 
In June 2017, for example, she fined Google €2.42 billion for abusing its market power by redirecting traffic from rival comparison shopping services to its own service, Froogle (which has since been renamed Google Product Search). The press release by the European Commission notes that Froogle entered the market in 2004, but struggled until Google demoted its competitors to the fourth page of search results. Froogle’s competitors consequently received less than one percent of traffic. A key piece of the commission’s argument was that Google’s anticompetitive behaviour harmed consumers. “[Google] denied European consumers a genuine choice of services and the full benefits of innovation,” says Vestager.
 
Other cases of anticompetitive behaviour by tech firms are harder to prove, largely because consumer harm is difficult to establish. According to standard economic theory, monopolies will maximise profit by increasing prices, thereby harming consumers. Thus, regulation is only necessary in the presence of high prices. However, some of today’s tech monopolies, such as Google and Facebook, provide free services, and others, such as Amazon, are operating at wafer-thin profits, suggesting predatory pricing.
 
A monopoly engages in predatory pricing when it prices its products below sustainable levels to drive out competitors, and then raises them back. For instance, Lina Khan, author of the widely acclaimed paper, “Amazon’s Antitrust Paradox,” outlines the story of Quidsi, an e-commerce platform specialising in baby products. After cutting its own baby-product prices by up to 30%, Amazon drove Quidsi to losses, acquired it and eventually scaled back the discounts.
 
Unlike those of traditional industries, the business models of tech companies are often predicated on predatory pricing. Tech companies aim to acquire scale rapidly by forsaking profitability, and investors are willing to finance them only if they can build scale. These unique features of tech companies make it difficult to rely on pricing as the main signal to detect harm to consumers. After all, when the price is zero, how can consumers be harmed? Yet, prices alone do not reflect the harm to consumers caused by less choice and innovation.
 
Another common tactic employed by tech companies is vertical integration, which is the acquisition of one firm in a certain stage of production by another firm in a different stage of production. By itself, it does not necessitate higher prices for consumers, but it does stifle competition. For example, Khan speculates that Amazon might purchase UPS and FedEx such that independent producers of competitive products have no choice but to deliver its products using Amazon. Resultantly, the e-commerce giant can establish itself as a monopoly, not raising prices, but gathering data about its competitors to price its own products more appealingly. Once again, consumers will be harmed by less innovation in the market.
 
The regulatory focus on proving harm to consumers through prices was established in the 1970s and has since become ineffective in promoting competition in tech markets. The repercussions of sclerotic competition are far-reaching as start-ups will be discouraged from entering the market, especially in America, where the focus is still on privacy and not on consumer harm. Regulators must scrutinize the actual harm caused by free products offered by these tech titans – after all, there is no such thing as a free lunch.
0 Comments

    Categories

    All
    Abenomics
    Adam Smith
    Adverse Selection
    Ageing
    Amazon
    Arrows
    Arthur Okun
    Asset
    Asymmetric Information
    Ben Bernanke
    Booms And Busts
    Braess' Paradox
    Brazil
    Bretton Woods
    Brexit
    Bubble
    Bull Market
    Business Cycle
    Capital Control
    Capital Flows
    Capital In The Twenty First Century
    Capital In The Twenty-First Century
    Carry Trade
    Causation
    Central Bank
    China
    Christopher Sims
    Classical Economics
    Consumption
    Counter-cyclical
    CPI
    Creative Destruction
    Crisis
    Daron Acemoglu
    David Cameron
    David Ricardo
    Debt
    Debt-to-GDP
    Deflation
    Deleverage Cycle
    Demography
    Devaluation
    Developing Economies
    Development
    Diffusion
    Diminishing Returns
    Dominant Strategy
    Dominated Strategy
    ECB
    Economic History
    Economic Theory
    Equality
    Equitity
    Equity
    Equity Investments
    EU
    Exchange Rate
    FDI
    Fed
    Federal Reserve
    Finance
    Financial Crisis
    Financial Instability Hypothesis
    Financial-instability Hypothesis
    Financial Times
    Fiscal Multiplier
    Fiscal Policy
    Fixed Exchange Rate
    Fleming
    Floating Exchange Rate
    Free Market
    Free Trade
    Freshwater
    Game Theory
    GDP
    George Akerlof
    Germany
    GFC
    Gini Coefficient
    Global Financial Crisis
    Globalization
    Government Intervention
    Government Spending
    Great Depression
    Growth
    Heckscher-Ohlin
    Helene Rey
    Hyman Minsky
    ICOR
    Illiquid
    Immigration
    Income
    Inequality
    Inflation
    Infrastructure
    Innovation
    Interest Rates
    Investment
    Italy
    James Robinson
    Janet Yellen
    Japan
    Jean Tirole
    J.M. Keynes
    John Nash
    Keynesian Economics
    Labor
    Lawrence Summers
    Leverage
    Lindau
    Liquid
    Malaysia
    Managed Exchange Rate
    Mario Draghi
    Matteo Renzi
    Michael Spense
    Minsky Moment
    Mixed Strategy
    Monetary Policy
    Monopoly
    Monopsony
    Moral Hazard
    Mundell
    Mundell-Fleming Trilemma
    Nash
    Nash Equilibrium
    Nigeria
    Nobel
    Nobel Laureates
    Nobel Prize
    Paul Krugman
    Paul Samuelson
    Perfect Information
    Phillips Curve
    Politics
    Poverty Traps
    Principal Agent Problem
    Prisoner's Dilemma
    Productivity
    Protectionism
    QE
    Qualitative Easing
    Quantitative Easing
    Redistribution
    Regulation
    Retrenching
    Rich
    Risk
    Robert Shiller
    Saltwater
    Saving
    Secular Stagnation
    Shiller
    Shinzo Abe
    Signaling
    Stakeholders
    Stolper-Samuelson Theorem
    Strategy
    Subsidies
    Tariff
    Taxation
    Taxes
    The Economist
    The Market For Lemons
    Theory Of Comparative Advantage
    Thomas Piketty
    Total Factor Productivity
    Trade
    Trilemma
    UK
    Unemployment
    U.S.
    USD
    Wage Benefits
    Wages
    Wealth
    Wealth Effect
    Wolfgang Stolper
    WTO
    Yuan

    Author

    JANANI DHILEEPAN
    A gap year student trying to explore real-world economics

    Archives

    May 2018
    February 2018
    January 2018
    December 2017
    November 2017
    April 2017
    February 2017
    December 2016
    October 2016
    September 2016
    August 2016
    July 2016
    May 2016
    March 2016
    January 2016
    November 2015
    September 2015
    August 2015
    July 2015
    June 2015
    April 2015
    March 2015
    February 2015
    January 2015
    December 2014
    November 2014
    October 2014
    September 2014

    RSS Feed

Proudly powered by Weebly